rabble blogs are the personal pages of some of Canada's most insightful progressive activists and commentators. All opinions belong to the writer; however, writers are expected to adhere to our guidelines. We welcome new bloggers -- contact us for details.

The Staple Theory at 50: The staples trap in developing countries

Photo: Mel Watkins

Here is an entry from the global South in our continuing series of commentaries marking the 50th anniversary of Mel Watkins' classic article, "A Staple Theory of Economic Growth." Dr. Alberto Daniel Gago teaches political economy at the National Universities of San Juan and Cuyo-Argentina.  He is a long-time collaborator of Mel's, and has written extensively about the challenges of development and diversification in Argentina. His commentary explores the relevance of staple theory for understanding the modern barriers to development in the South.

In 1980 I first encountered the work of Mel Watkins, while I was completing my Master's thesis on the theory of regional export base, applied to the Cuyo region of Argentina, at the Institute of Social Studies in the Netherlands. Indeed, Mel's classic paper, "A Staple Theory of Economic Growth," has been very influential in the whole Latin American school of economic development theory.

Watkins' approach allowed us to leave aside the neoclassical theory of export base, brought more complexity to the analysis of staples-driven growth, and highlighted the range and contingency of possible outcomes to the development process. He coined the term "staples trap" to refer to the inability of a resource-based economy to mature into a diverse and industrialized one. Overspecialization in export-oriented staples implies dependence on foreign direct investment, while under-privileging domestic manufacturing and economic diversification.

In regions with resource-intensive production, economic growth is strongly concentrated on staples, produced for export to more highly developed regions. This supposedly paves the way for broader economic growth, and implies a resource-intensive strategy for national and regional development based on external markets. However, this optimistic story is incomplete.

In countries open to global markets, staples industries produce deep structural economic, political, social and cultural changes:

- In a global era, staples industries typically rely on multinational corporations, that appropriate profit through their direct investments in staples projects. Transnational corporations control the overall staple trajectory, giving them a leadership role in the overall economic and political dynamic that does not necessarily serve the broader interests of the host economy well.

- These large global corporations also tend to absorb and exclude small and medium firms from the formal production system. The multinational corporations, from their dominant position, transform the regional production system into oligopolies, ultimately controlling the natural resources and capturing the resulting economic surplus.

- Peripheral capitalist regions dependent on staples fail to develop into full-fledged industrialized economies; these countries can be caught in a circle of economic re-primarization and de-industrialization.

- Instead of promoting broader economic diversification, multinational corporations strengthen only a few specialized productive branches and activities within the peripheral capitalist regions.

- The resulting concentration and centralization of economic power produces a dialectical process of economic, social, political and cultural fragmentation -- and in the long term leads to instability.

In this sense, Mel's "Staple Theory" helped us to understand the implications and limitations of staples-led development, and spurred an intellectual focus on the "staple trap" and its causes. Topics for this inquiry included better understanding the forward and backward linkages to staples industries, the relationship between staples and broader domestic development, the role and influence of the new elites and investment groups, impact of staples-dependence on overall modernization, and the underlying conditions (values, institutions, and public policies) necessary for staples-led growth.

In Argentina, for instance, the latest international structural adjustments provoked deep changes in the national and regional economies. These developments spurred us to analyze the recent processes of economic and social development in the Cuyo region (in the western part of Argentina). Structural transformations have been imposed by the internationalization of production, markets and capital, helped by national policies which reinforced the dominance of international corporations.

It is necessary to understand how developing regions are incorporated into the new trajectory of the global economy. New questions for inquiry arise, including: Where and how are new organizations are shaped? How does overspecialization work, and how are its consequences manifested? Who are the dominant actors in the global staple exports chain, and how is their influence experienced in particular staples producing regions?

The behavior of staples, and specifically the "staple trap," inherently directs this analysis away from the neoclassical approach. For this reason, staples theorists in the south have also incorporated the main themes of the French Regulation school, in order to better comprehend the staples-driven economic growth process. Three of these complementary regulationist themes are: modernization, accumulation and regulation.

1. Modernization suggests that the staples-led development process is reliant on technological innovation imported from leading developed countries. In fact, the large corporations that control the staple economy benefit most from modernization, since they are able to arrange their export goods production on the basis of the advanced technology they apply to staple and complementary industries. Through capital accumulation and their access to the economic and information networks, they come to dominate world staple markets.

2. The accumulation process in staples industries reveals how hegemonic and dominant groups base their power on unequal social relations of production, income distribution, and surplus concentration. The interrelation among fractions of capital varies according to the regime of accumulation. The regime of accumulation refers to the way the dominant economic forces operate within a given mode of production, including their trade strategies, their pattern of capital, and their processes of production. Accumulation is controlled by great firms which manipulate the production process and exert the dominance of staples over the main economic branches. The accumulation process reflects, in turn, several more key considerations:

- The generation of surplus at the moment of production (through inputs of labor and capital);

- The relationships between production, distribution and consumption, shaped by social relations that permit the realization and subsequent recycling of the social surplus; and

- The ultimate utilization of social surplus, which can take different modalities according to the regime of accumulation and the mode of governmental regulation.

Through these channels, the overall dynamic of accumulation fundamentally reflects the staple-export chain. In short, the entire modes of regulation and accumulation are organized around staple industries. Obviously, this organization depends on the historical moment, on the kind of technological innovation imposed on the export economic branches, and on the economic agents leading this process.

3. Finally, it is important to understand the role of regulation and the state in shaping the overall staple development process. According to the staple thesis, state actions tend to follow from their overall priority on facilitating the staple trade. These actions include provision of transportation infrastructure for the export of the staple; underwriting monetary obligations through the availability of credit guarantees and liquidity; and, as export demand shifts, aiding adjustment from declining to rising staple sectors. These actions highlight the conscious decisions of state and business elites to permit the internationalization of capital and the resulting staples-dependence. Political life is thus deeply influenced by staple exports, because economic wealth and political power are so concentrated in business and political elites (who are often the same people). In this way, the state synthesizes power relations through laws, decrees and regulations, in an attempt to adapt the behavior of social agents, given the staples orientation of the domestic economy, to changes in the international economy.

The global staple chain: Production, firms and capital

Production and accumulation circuits are also influenced by national macro policies and international trade. At the same time, it is important to recognize the exchange relations between the sub-national, national, and international spaces -- in terms of both production processes and capital accumulation. To understand the contradictions and political struggles that entail, the analysis must explain the ways in which agents alter or preserve their positions within staple sectors, and then extend that power across regional, national and international spaces.

By emphasizing staples activities related to natural resources (such as agriculture, agro-industry, mining and petroleum), accumulation is controlled by large firms that articulate their influence into many different sectors (including resources, industry, and finance). This leads to the devaluation of other segments of capital, negatively affected by the dominance of the global staples chain, producing social costs, obsolescence, and massive unemployment.

In developing regions like Cuyo, a process of concentration and centralization of foreign capital occurs among economic branches. Multinational corporations control the distribution and commercialization phases of the staple industry (both national and international).

The staple theory was constructed on a systematic account of staples exploitation, transportation, and market demands. But it is also necessary to emphasize the distribution of social surplus among firms and among classes, and the resulting distribution of power, to explain the overall trajectory of economic growth. Obviously, it is necessary to link staples firms with banks and other economic branches.

Government is essential to the coordination of transnational production systems, in terms of managing the overall mode of regulation, and promoting the location of large transnational corporations which play the central role in staples production. The main functions of global enterprises are to facilitate a transition from producer-driven to buyer-driven supply chains. But these firms also relate among themselves, belong to the same lobby groups, and promote similar interests. The regional export and natural resource bases are thus appropriated by national and international holdings. This partly explains the presence of foreign capital in agriculture, agro-industry, mining and petroleum. This process of globalization is further accelerated by state reforms and deregulation.

This panorama is completed with the shift of other agents as consequence of the lack of capital valuation within their own firms and sectors. Small scale firms are at a disadvantage, caught in a vicious circle: they cannot attract innovative managers, invest in the modernization of plant and equipment, or implement new technological advances. Then they are relegated to a battle for survival in the informal sector, facing continuously deteriorating conditions of unemployment and marginal self-employment.

Modernity is represented by so called "bubbles of wealth," expensive new residences and facilities built to keep ordinary people away and avoid social conflict -- such as the increasing prevalence of condominiums and private residential neighborhoods highly controlled by security apparatus. At the opposite end of the spectrum is the withdrawal of producers and workers from the rural to the urban areas, and the ever-present unemployed workforce -- so-called "bubbles of poverty."

To sum up, the globalization modernization process provokes increasing inequality and social polarization. Without changes in public policies aimed at improving the distribution of social and economic resources, social conflict remains a permanent feature of the staples-dependent developing economy.

Research we are currently conducting at the National University in Argentina further develops the analysis of staples industries and resource-intensive development in peripheral capitalistic regions. We pay close attention to the processes observed in recent decades following structural adjustment and globalization. Our key findings include:

- Staples industries generally failed to branch into mature manufacturing because they became caught in a "staples trap," resulting mostly from the dominance of large foreign capital.

- Technologically, staples industries are led by large international firms, which own and develop the technology.

- Developing countries and regions are attempting to complete the transition to industrial capitalism, at a time when the strongest sections of world capitalism were themselves undergoing intensive concentration and centralization. This makes the transition all the more challenging.

- Profound instability results when the staple growth model changes due to external causes.

- Public policies, values and institutions reinforce economic concentration in the wake of the shifting conditions of internationalization.

Social and economic development as a result of the internationalization of staples production, and the success of export activities and competitive specialization in staples, foster an apparent modernization of the peripheral regions, in line with the shifting conditions of imperial relations. This is a turning point, which helps to explain the dynamics of capital accumulation, the consolidation of the agents' positions in the global supply chain, the growth of some economic branches (but the shrinkage of others), and the role of the state. This is a dialectical process in which both the productive forces and social relations represent the conflicted integration process of the overall system.

While 50 years have passed since Mel's seminal paper, his pioneering analysis of the "staple trap" has kept its value in the development studies literature. It helps us understand the overall matrix of resource-intensive export production, and its impacts on production, accumulation and policy -- outcomes that are still strongly visible in many developing countries, including Argentina.

Thank you for reading this story…

More people are reading rabble.ca than ever and unlike many news organizations, we have never put up a paywall – at rabble we’ve always believed in making our reporting and analysis free to all, while striving to make it sustainable as well. Media isn’t free to produce. rabble’s total budget is likely less than what big corporate media spend on photocopying (we kid you not!) and we do not have any major foundation, sponsor or angel investor. Our main supporters are people and organizations -- like you. This is why we need your help. You are what keep us sustainable.

rabble.ca has staked its existence on you. We live or die on community support -- your support! We get hundreds of thousands of visitors and we believe in them. We believe in you. We believe people will put in what they can for the greater good. We call that sustainable.

So what is the easy answer for us? Depend on a community of visitors who care passionately about media that amplifies the voices of people struggling for change and justice. It really is that simple. When the people who visit rabble care enough to contribute a bit then it works for everyone.

And so we’re asking you if you could make a donation, right now, to help us carry forward on our mission. Make a donation today.

Comments

We welcome your comments! rabble.ca embraces a pro-human rights, pro-feminist, anti-racist, queer-positive, anti-imperialist and pro-labour stance, and encourages discussions which develop progressive thought. Our full comment policy can be found here. Learn more about Disqus on rabble.ca and your privacy here. Please keep in mind:

Do

  • Tell the truth and avoid rumours.
  • Add context and background.
  • Report typos and logical fallacies.
  • Be respectful.
  • Respect copyright - link to articles.
  • Stay focused. Bring in-depth commentary to our discussion forum, babble.

Don't

  • Use oppressive/offensive language.
  • Libel or defame.
  • Bully or troll.
  • Post spam.
  • Engage trolls. Flag suspect activity instead.